Globalization has been hailed by many as a remarkable system for more efficient global allocation of resources. However, financial globalization has been accompanied by frequent and painful financial crises. Since the debt crises of 1982, financial crises have occurred every now and then. Some of the most famous ones are Mexican crisis in 1995, East Asian crisis in 1997, Russian crisis in 1998, Turkish crisis in 1994 and 2001, Brazilian crisis in 1999, Argentine crisis in 2002 and the current crises which has the unique feature of having originated in the developed countries.
The developing countries found a way to protect themselves from such crises and the painful process of IMF conditionalities by accumulating reserves. Countries with higher level of liquid foreign assets are able to withstand panics and sudden reversal of capital flows. Therefore, developing countries including
There are essentially three ways in which the cost of holding excess foreign exchange reserves can be ascertained.
- The spread between the private sector’s cost of short-term borrowing abroad and the yield that the Central Bank earns on its liquid foreign assets.
- The spread between the interest on domestic government bonds and the yield on reserves. This is known as the fiscal cost of reserves.
- Lastly, reserves could have been alternatively used to augment the public capital stock of the economy, and the social opportunity cost of (public) capital can be used as the relevant benchmark for the cost of foreign borrowing.
The objective of this paper is to compute the first kind of cost i.e. spread between the private sector’s cost of short-term borrowing abroad and the yield that the Central Bank earns on its liquid foreign assets for
Phenomenal growth of Reserves
Prior to the era of financial globalization, countries held reserves mainly to manage foreign exchange demand and supply arising from current account transactions. The traditional rule of thumb for Central Banks was that they should hold a quantity of foreign exchange reserves equivalent to three months of imports. However, in the age of financial liberalization when panics and sudden reversal of capital flows are very common this rule of thumb was clearly insufficient. All developing saw the advantage of holding a large stock of international reserves to protect their domestic financial system without IMF cooperation. Infact the policy guideline that the IMF provided to the developing countries with uncertain access to capital markets also encouraged the accumulation of reserves equal to short term debt. The rule that countries should hold liquid reserves equal to their foreign liabilities coming due within a year is known as the Guidotti-Greenspan rule.
The Cost of Reserve Holdings
The natural question that arises in this exercise is what constitutes optimal amount of reserves. However, there is no clear answer to this question because even countries with sound macroeconomic policies can be hit by contagion from elsewhere in the world of liberalization. Hence the bench mark for optimal reserves keeps increasing. Keeping in mind the self – insurance motive it is assumed that the optimal amount of reserves equals the sum of short term debt, six months of imports and foreign portfolio investments. Reserves in excess of this amount are considered unnecessary. With this definition of optimal reserves, I find that excess reserves have been increasing steadily from negative levels in 1991 – 92 to a high of US$ 140,076 mn in India.
To ascertain the loss in income associated with holding excess reserves, potential investment rate has been calculated by adding excess reserves as a percentage of GDP to the actual rate of growth of investment. Once this potential investment rate has been calculated, the potential rate of growth of GDP can be calculated by dividing potential investment rate by the incremental capital output ration. The loss in growth is the difference between the potential growth rate and the actual growth rate (Table 1.).
Table 1.
Year Rate of NDCF ROG of GDP at FC Excess Reserves/ GDP Potential Growth Rate Loss of Growth 1991-92 12.7 1.4 -4% 0.98 -0.45 1992-93 13.5 5.4 -2% 4.57 -0.79 1993-94 13.7 5.7 2% 6.51 0.83 1994-95 17.1 6.4 3% 7.51 1.12 1995-96 17.2 7.3 1% 7.71 0.42 1996-97 15.2 8 0% 7.97 - 1997-98 16.9 4.3 1% 4.56 0.25 1998-99 15.3 6.7 2% 7.56 0.87 1999-00 18.3 6.4 2% 7.14 0.7 2000-01 16 4.4 3% 5.17 0.81 2001-02 13.8 5.8 6% 8.34 2.53 2002-03 16.6 3.8 9% 5.92 2.08 2003-04 19 8.5 14% 14.81 6.29 2004-05 22.7 7.5 14% 12.08 4.61 2005-06 25.8 9.5 11% 13.57 4.05 2006-07 27 9.7 14% 14.8 5.05 2007-08 28.9 9 19% 14.94 5.93
*Figure in parentheses indicate negative values
The loss of GDP growth has been increasing with the increase in reserve holdings. The percentage loss in GDP growth was 5.93% in 2007 – 08 and the loss was highest in the year 2003 – 04 at 6.29%.
The above analysis proves that
A study (Fan, Hazell and Thorat, 1999) carried out by the International Food Policy Research Institute on linkages between government expenditure and poverty in rural
Table 2. No. of people out of poverty with investment in Roads equivalent to Excess Reserves
Year | Inv. In Roads/Excess reserves | Number of people out of poverty | |
1991-92 | -9,886.25 | -16,31,231 | |
1992-93 | -6,213.25 | -10,25,186 | |
1993-94 | 4,686.20 | 7,73,223 | |
1994-95 | 9,263.90 | 15,28,544 | |
1995-96 | 2,325.80 | 3,83,757 | |
1996-97 | 130.79 | 21,581.17 | |
1997-98 | 3,578.76 | 5,90,494.6 | |
1998-99 | 6,908.65 | 11,39,926 | |
1999-00 | 9,233.97 | 15,23,605 | |
2000-01 | 13,384.78 | 22,08,488 | |
2001-02 | 25,654.36 | 42,32,969 | |
2002-03 | 40,384.93 | 66,63,513 | |
2003-04 | 69,453.45 | 1,14,59,818 | |
2004-05 | 78,226.29 | 1,29,07,337 | |
2005-06 | 68,343.14 | 1,12,76,617 | |
2006-07 | 94,340.38 | 1,55,66,163 | |
2007-08 | 140,076.00 | 2,31,12,539 |
In 2007 – 08 the amount of excess reserves held with Reserve bank of